000 | 01994nam a22002177a 4500 | ||
---|---|---|---|
999 |
_c3596 _d3596 |
||
005 | 20230103155219.0 | ||
008 | 230103b ||||| |||| 00| 0 eng d | ||
020 | _a9780691003542 | ||
082 |
_a332.4973 _bFRI |
||
100 |
_aFriedman, Milton _94515 |
||
245 | _aA monetary history of the United states, 1867-1960 | ||
260 |
_bPrinceton University Press _aPrinceton _c1993 |
||
300 | _axxiv, 860 p. | ||
365 |
_aUSD _b69.95 |
||
520 | _aWriting in the June 1965 issue of theEconomic Journal, Harry G. Johnson begins with a sentence seemingly calibrated to the scale of the book he set himself to review: “The long-awaited monetary history of the United States by Friedman and Schwartz is in every sense of the term a monumental scholarly achievement — monumental in its sheer bulk, monumental in the definitiveness of its treatment of innumerable issues, large and small … monumental, above all, in the theoretical and statistical effort and ingenuity that have been brought to bear on the solution of complex and subtle economic issues.” Friedman and Schwartz marshaled massive historical data and sharp analytics to support the claim that monetary policy — steady control of the money supply — matters profoundly in the management of the nation’s economy, especially in navigating serious economic fluctuations. In their influential chapter 7, The Great Contraction — which Princeton published in 1965 as a separate paperback — they address the central economic event of the century, the Depression. According to Hugh Rockoff, writing in January 1965: “If Great Depressions could be prevented through timely actions by the monetary authority (or by a monetary rule), as Friedman and Schwartz had contended, then the case for market economies was measurably stronger.” | ||
650 |
_aMonetary policy _92120 |
||
650 |
_aCurrency question _95258 |
||
650 |
_aBanks and banking _9442 |
||
700 |
_aSchwartz, Anna _911225 |
||
942 |
_2ddc _cBK |